A while back, Dick Locke, who has an entire state on his side, wrote a great post on the importance of plain English in contracts that I’m betting many of you didn’t take seriously enough. To help you understand why this is very important, here’s a short video from The Temp Life that describes what might happen if you don’t follow his advice:
Monthly Archives: May 2010
What Would Happen if Google Took Privacy Lessons from Facebook?
To help you put into real terms what Facebook’s recent actions on privacy really mean, here’s what would likely happen if Google took privacy lessons from Facebook. (A tip of the hat to SuperNews for this crystal clear analogy.)
Should You Use Seller Side Auctions for Your Commodity Buys?
A recent article over on Industry Week (Not Your Fathers Auction) trumpeted the benefits of Seller Side Auctions (SSAs) for commodity sales over traditional negotiations, indicating that the more open and transparent process they enabled bring with it a number of benefits that include:
- refocused sales resources on higher margin activitiesan auction reduces the time and direct costs associated with commodity transactions which allows sales teams to focus on custom products and value-added services
- improved revenue visibility and forecast accuracybilateral contracting standardizes terms and conditions across customers, simplifying revenue visibility and visibility and eliminating the invisible risk created by bilateral contracts with customized, non-standard, terms and conditions
- reduced renegotiation riskinconsistency leads to errors, which start disputes, renegotiations, and, sometimes, even litigation
- improved customer relationshipsbuyers and sellers are no longer adversarial, the buyers are competing against other buyers, not the seller … which lays the foundation for a better relationship going forward
- reduced price barriers and market intelligenceauctions greatly reduce the acquisition cost as well as the cost of market intelligence
- new customer acquisition and penetration into underserved market segmentsincreased efficiency allows the supplier to serve market segments which might otherwise be too costly to serve
But what about the buyer? What benefits do they get beyond market intelligence (and what their competitors are willing to pay)? The relationships will be more cordial, but if it’s a commodity, the supplier will not be strategic and there is no obvious value from a good relationship. They will get a more efficient process, but they would also get that if they just held their own auction and invited suppliers to participate. So where’s the real value?
From a buyer’s perspective, the real value is quality merchandise at true market cost at great efficiency. If a buyer holds an auction and the only suppliers who participate are those that produce lower quality products and/or those that can only produce small volumes, the buyer might get stuck with lower quality products or having to buy from multiple suppliers, which will increase total cost of ownership (with increased service and warranty costs, logistics costs, and even product costs if the suppliers don’t have the economies of scale). But if their supplier(s) of choice are holding auctions, they can participate in those auctions and obtain the commodity products at true market cost, which is always set by the buying organizations. Furthermore, the buyer doesn’t have to waste her organization’s resources setting up and holding the auction. All she has to do is bid. And if she loses the bid with the first choice supplier, she moves on to the second choice supplier.
It’s an interesting idea, and one that deserves further consideration.
Is the West Going to Lose the Talent War?
I have to say that I’m worried after reading “grow, grow, grow” in the special report on innovation and emerging markets in the April 17th edition of The Economist. Near the end of the article we are told, point blank, that the best companies in emerging markets treat “talent” as a supply chain that needs to be relentlessly managed, not an isolated problem that can be solved on a piecemeal basis and that firms invest heavily in creating “educational ecosystems”.
While the first thing we do is slash the training budget every time money gets tight, companies in eastern emerging countries dispatch managers to give speeches at Universities. For example, GE has charged its top ten managers in China with cultivating relations with a particular university where they can spot bright youngsters and treat them to campus tours and scholarships (that will grow the brand and attract these future superstars).
While we expect unreasonable exceptional performance for a meager base salary and verbally lash out at anyone who doesn’t exceed her performance metrics by at least 10%, eastern emerging companies celebrate good performers. Haier prominently displays photographs of good performing managers, celebrates outstanding innovators in public ceremonies, and names new products and business innovations after their creators.
While we still assign undue praise to the University you attended instead of the degree you earned, your GPA, or, more importantly, what you actually learned, Infosys has adopted the mantra of “no caste, no creed, only merit” for its modern campus in Mysore. Furthermore, to ensure its employees had a better chance of not only climbing the ladder but becoming a millionaire than if they worked for a foreign multinational, Infosys was one of the first Indian companies to issue stock options.
And while we are the first to walk our best talent out the door every time the market dips, even though we just told them they were our most valuable asset the day before (as we, obviously, lied through our teeth), companies in emerging countries, who are experiencing much more rapid turnover than we need to deal with, will stick by their talent through thick and thin — cutting staff is the absolute last resort, not the first.
All told, it looks to me like we’re going to lose the talent war, which means that we’re also going to lose the innovation war, which we were supposed to win by outsourcing all of the manufacturing and back office to focus on our “core strengths” which, apparently, is middle management, junior art directorship and telephone cleaning, as that’s all we will be able to do if we don’t start focussing on talent, the true producer of innovation.
What is The Price of Flexible Supply Chains? Part V: Eternal Vigilance
In this post, I’m going to discuss highlights from the CPO Executive Debate on “the price of flexible supply chains” and focus on why you have to be eternally vigilant.
Getting straight to the point, in response to how does emergence from the recession affect supply chain flexibility, Andrew Vaughan noted that there is a dynamism in the whole supply chain piece and therefore you have got to keep reviewing it constantly. Raw material shortages can bring an end to a product’s life, earthquakes can take out factories, and bankruptcies can take out suppliers literally overnight. One day your supply chain is running like a well-made Swiss timepiece … the next day it’s brought to a screeching halt as your fine tuned Ferrari slams into a brick wall.
Even if you, as Colin Davis points out, maintained a reasonably broad supply chain during the recession and maybe compromised some of the commercial advantages you could have taken in those situations so that you can then call on people as you go forward, if your suppliers or partners are in worse shape than you are, despite their good intentions, they might not be able to respond to the call. The safety net you think you have can be taken down at any time. Just like that information flow you painstakingly set up can disappear over night if you built it on a proprietary copper network which was just dug up and sold for scrap.
Furthermore, you need to keep an eye on the entire supply chain, which, as Andrew Vaughan points out, doesn’t necessarily end when you get the product delivered to the installer or customer. For many products, there is also the service chain to consider. Whereas many customers will just as happily trade up to a new model when their current cell phone dies, most customers want to keep their cars and high end (Apple) computers for a few years (or more). You need to be able to provide them with parts and services quickly when they need maintenance or repairs … because it all affects your image as a provider of quality goods and services.
Furthermore, not only do really advanced procurement supply chain organisations understand today the ripple effects that a natural disaster, or an epidemic, has on their overall supply chain, and take immediate preventative action even though only a sub-tier supplier to their main supply base is directly affected, as Martin Hogel notes, but these organizations also know that a ripple effect can start anywhere … even in the retail stores. For example, retailers can notice that product sales for a new category of product, like e-readers, is heating up across the board. They place orders into distributors for more product, who place orders into manufacturers for even more product, who place orders into component suppliers for much more flash memory, which is in limited supply. In this classic bullwhip effect scenario, the flash manufacturers will quickly sell out of all available inventory, and an artificial shortage will be created in the market. Those manufacturers who are not vigilant will not be among the first to get their orders in, their products will be delayed, and this will likely result in lost sales.
All in all, the need for eternal vigilance — in addition to strategy, customer obsession, and a strong supply base — is pretty clear and the debate (on the price of flexible supply chains) was quite an interesting one. If you haven’t yet done so, and can spare the time, I’d strongly recommend that you check the entire debate on the price of flexible supply chains and join in the discussion. It’s your supply chain on the line.